Robert Skidelsky: Greek crisis lays bare the failure of European project

DRAMATIC challenges, and mediocre responses: that is the history of the European Union. All too rarely does the EU rise to the level of events, which is why Europe is fading economically and geopolitically.

The 1958 Treaty of Rome, which established the European Economic Community, was Europe's great leap forward. But creating a common market without a common government was simply storing up trouble for the future. Everything since – enlargement to 27 member states and the creation of the 16-member eurozone – has widened the gap between rhetoric and reality. Euroland has gone on promising far more than its history enables it to deliver.

The Greek financial crisis is the latest example of the gap between reality and rhetoric. At root, it is a crisis of "enlargement", in this case enlargement of the eurozone. Unprecedented effort at fiscal discipline in the 1990s – helped in Greece by creative accounting – enabled Portugal, Italy, Greece and Spain to meet the entry criteria in 2002. But once in, the pressure was off. Most of the Mediterranean countries continued on their spendthrift ways.

Hide Ad
Hide Ad

Now Wolfgang Schauble, Germany's finance minister, has said enough is enough. He advocates setting up a European Monetary Fund (EMF) to provide emergency lending to countries at risk of default on their sovereign debt. Emergency lending would come with a "prohibitive price tag", "strict conditions" and "mandatory penalties" in the event of non-compliance. Translated into ordinary language, this means the state finances of a country that was granted help from the EMF would be outsourced, for a time, to external commissioners.

Milton Friedman predicted the single currency would fall apart after a decade or two; this is now more likely than not. After all, Schauble knows the conditions he proposes would be politically unacceptable, so he says any country unable to meet them "should, as a last resort, exit the monetary union, while being able to remain a member of the EU".

The Mediterranean crisis has exposed the eurozone's long-standing flaw: the absence of a single government. Because the eurozone is not an "optimal currency area", it needs tools to deal with so-called "asymmetric shocks" – shocks that affect some members more than others. But it lacks those tools, especially a Treasury with powers to tax and borrow, and a central bank that can act as lender of last resort.

Schauble's proposal has both an economic and a geopolitical dimension. Economically, it exposes the deep divide between those who believe that external imbalances are the fault of those who spend too little and those who believe that they are the fault of those who spend too much.

John Maynard Keynes wanted to force surplus countries to either spend or lend. But the older doctrine that it was a deficit country's duty to "put its house in order" survived. The one concession to Keynes was the creation of the International Monetary Fund in 1944 in order to provide short-term assistance to deficit countries under strict conditions. This, in essence, is the German proposal today.

Schauble's view is an expression of Germany's long-standing deflationary outlook. Germany's fiscally conservative establishment would like other EU countries with large budget deficits to return to economic health through fiscal discipline, reduced domestic demand and high export growth. The problem, German leaders believe, is not their country's high saving rate, but other eurozone members' excessive spending.

The main impact of Schauble's bombshell is on the geopolitics of the EU. Europe's political elite view the union as one of the poles in a multi-polar world. But what is Europe? Less than a federation, more than a confederation, it lacks any centre of gravity, any fixed frontiers. When an American, Chinese, or Russian leader wants to speak to Europe, whom does he call? Without internal coherence or external shape, Europe is little more than a geographical expression.

The implication of Schauble's proposition, therefore, is that Euroland should shrink to a governable dimension. In essence, it recapitulates the contrast between the Greater Germany dreamed of by idealists in 1848 and the Smaller Germany created by Bismarck in 1871.

Hide Ad
Hide Ad

Like the little boy who was unafraid to declare the emperor naked, Schauble has pointed the finger of realism at the aspirational rhetoric in which all European leaders are still compelled to clothe their utterances. He has broken with the taboo against calling into doubt any aspect of the European project.

For those who prefer solid construction to wishful thinking, his words are to be welcomed.

• Lord Skidelsky is professor emeritus of political economy at Warwick University, author of a biography of the economist John Maynard Keynes, and a board member of the Moscow School of Political Studies.

Related topics: